Evaluation Criteria Prior to 2016
This is an archived version of the Recommendation Criteria used prior to our 2016 recommendations.
Recommendation Criteria for Animal Advocacy Charities
1. The organization has concrete room for more funding and plans for growth. It has plans that cannot be fully accomplished with the expected funding from other sources, and the barriers to accomplishing those plans are monetary, not due to time, a lack of qualified personnel, or other non-monetary issues. Receiving money from donors directed by ACE would be very likely to increase the organization’s total impact.
2. A back-of-the-envelope calculation finds the organization is cost-effective. Considering the organization’s budget and its demonstrated successes, the organization appears to be cost-effective in the goal of reducing animal suffering, relative to other organizations. If these calculations were produced with perfect information, they would be the only factor necessary to consider beyond room for more funding. However, because our calculations are necessarily estimates, corroborative evidence is required.
3. The organization is working on things that seem to have high mission effectiveness. Without considering the specific implementation, the interventions pursued by the organization are among those expected to be highly effective. Often this information will come partly from our intervention evaluation process. At the very least, the organization is working in a domain with high potential for efficiency (for instance, farmed animal advocacy) or is working in another domain with methods that appear to be exceptionally cost-effective.
4. The organization possesses a robust and agile understanding of success and failure. The organization has both short- and long-term goals and can articulate signs that indicate whether they are moving towards or away from their goals. Regular self-assessments guide the organization’s program development. If applicable, the organization has responded appropriately in the past to signs that a program was not succeeding.
5. The organization possesses a strong track record of success. The organization has a record of successful achievement of incremental goals or of demonstrated progress towards larger goals. Note that this implies the organization has been in existence for some length of time. While very young organizations may have strong potential to return large results for small initial amounts of funding, donating to organizations without track records is inherently risky.
6. The organization has strong organizational leadership and structure. The current leaders of the organization seem competent and well-respected. The organization has structures in place to train staff and volunteers (as appropriate) and to ensure continuity through staff transitions.
7. The organization is transparent. The organization freely provides information about its activities upon request or, better, makes such information publicly available. The organization is open about past successes and failures.
This is an archived version of the Detailed Criteria for Evaluating Potential Organizations used prior to our 2016 recommendations.
1. Criteria for Evaluating Potential Organizations
Before Animal Charity Evaluators (ACE) selects which organizations to recommend, it is beneficial to transparently establish what criteria we will aim to rank organizations on and how we intend to assess that criteria. Below, we outline and elaborate upon seven different criteria.
It’s worth noting that right now how to weigh each criterion relative to the others is subjective. While we’ve worked hard to standardize our opinions, it’s just too difficult of a judgment call to write up explicitly how these trade-offs will be navigated, and instead the best we can expect to do is make calls on a case-by-case basis as we start evaluating organizations. We’ll definitely learn a lot from actually undertaking this process, and we expect our criteria to change as ACE gets more experience evaluating organizations.
- Criterion #1: The Organization Has Concrete Room for More Funding and Plans for Growth
- Criterion #2: A Back-of-the-Envelope Calculation Finds the Organization is Cost-Effective
- Criterion #3: The Organization is Working on Things That Seem to Have High Mission Effectiveness
- Criterion #4: The Organization Possesses A Robust and Agile Understanding of Success and Failure
- Criterion #5: The Organization Possesses a Strong Track Record of Success
- Criterion #6: The Organization Has Strong Organizational Leadership and Structure
- Criterion #7: The Organization is Transparent
- II.The Cost-Effectiveness Calculation
I.1. Criterion #1: The Organization Has Concrete Room for More Funding and Plans for Growth
The first criterion we need to look at is whether the organization has room for more funding and plans for growth. When it comes to deciding where to allocate donations, it doesn’t matter how effective an organization is if they have no use for additional donations.
I.1.a. Why might an organization not have room for more funding?
For an organization, there can be more bottlenecks to expanding their operations than just money. Some organizations may have a lot of money available to expand programs but not have the talent they need to logistically manage that expansion, or may be restricted by government legislation, or the inability to make partnerships with other groups, or any of a variety of different problems. For example, GiveWell once found that non-profit Smile Train had a bunch of money, but weren’t able to use it to hire needed developing-world doctors because the supply had been used up and there weren’t any more available to hire. More recently, GiveWell also found a similar problem with immunizations and micronutrient supplementations—there’s lots of money in this area, but there are logistical problems in creating the needed partnerships with the country governments, and these are problems that only time—not more money—can solve.
When evaluating the work of organizations focused on nonhuman animals, we need to make sure that even if we find something effective, that the intervention in question is bottlenecked specifically by money and that more money is what will make the intervention happen. Otherwise, donations might not be what the organization needs and it would be counter-productive to recommend them to donors.
I.1.b. How can we evaluate the organization for room for more funding?
The first way to evaluate room for more funding is to look at patterns in the financial data of the non-profit. In particular, we could check to make sure the amount of assets they hold is not unusually large relative to the size of the organization and see if the organization has been expanding in past years. It would be good to check this on both the level of the organization as a whole and the level of individual programs / interventions, if applicable.
The second method is to ask the non-profit directly. In GiveWell’s first year of research, they would ask as a part of their grant application process, “What would a significant increase in funding allow your organization to do that it couldn’t do otherwise?” Questions might get more specific about what an organization would do with certain levels of funding, for example, asking “what would your organization do with a one-time donation of $10K?” Though one must be careful as organizations may have a tendency to tell the donor what they think the donor wants to hear.
I.1.c. How can we evaluate other aspects of room for more funding?
It’s not enough to evaluate room for more funding from the organization itself, however. Instead, one must also understand the risk that another donor would donate to the organization if ACE were not to move money to it. For example, before GiveWell could finish considering non-profit GAVI for a recommendation, its $3.5B funding gap was completely filled by other donors.
Given that ACE is making donor recommendations this might not be an issue, but a large donor could potentially take out the room for more funding before ACE-directed donors could fill it. Thus, understanding the potential funding landscape for an organization by seeing what other funders in the space are doing is also important.
I.2. Criterion #2: A Back-of-the-Envelope Calculation Finds the Organization is Cost-Effective
I.2.a. What goes into a back-of-the-envelope calculation?
The goal of the back-of-the-envelope calculation is to explicitly answer the question “How cost-effective is a donation to this organization / intervention, given what we know?” This is accomplished by creating an equation to get a figure of “years of nonhuman animal suffering averted per dollar”, which is a figure that appropriately takes into account the differences between nonhuman animals.
A lot of work would need to go into developing what this calculation would look like, how it would be adapted to different interventions, and how the information to complete the equation would be completed and updated. Because it’s so complex, we have devoted an additional section to it (see section II).
I.2.b. Why is a back-of-the-envelope calculation not enough?
In a perfect world with no uncertainty, a back-of-the-envelope calculation would be all that is needed to evaluate an organization. Indeed, one might be tempted to think that if we have a sufficient guess as to how many years of nonhuman animal suffering are averted, we have all we need to compare organizations and can just go with whichever one appears the most cost-effective. However, for reasons discussed by GiveWell in “Why We Can’t Take Expected Value Estimates Literally” and by Peter Hurford in “Why I’m Skeptical About Unproven Causes”, this is naïve.
Put simply, there is a lot of opportunity for bias in cost-effectiveness measures, and measures generally need to be “regressed back to the mean” to adjust for bias and uncertainty. Therefore, we need to look at other criteria in order to calibrate our estimate.
Another possible way of thinking about this is that we are creating many weak arguments in favor of a particular non-profit rather than one strong argument, which is the best we can do under the uncertainty that we will presumably be operating under.
I.2.c. How do we move beyond the back-of-the-envelope calculation?
First, we define the following terms:
management effectiveness: an organization has high management effectiveness if it is well-run, well-managed, and accomplishes its mission as best as possible with its given resources.
mission effectiveness: an organization has high mission effectiveness if it has picked a mission that is the most effective mission at reducing the suffering of nonhuman animals.
These concepts are distinct. We could have an organization that has high mission effectiveness yet low management effectiveness—when it comes to public health, think an anti-malaria organization that wastes 90% of its money and staff time on fundraisers with incredibly poor returns and only uses 10% on net distribution.
We also could have an organization that has low mission effectiveness yet high management effectiveness—when it comes to public health, think an organization that is focused on fighting breast cancer, yet is highly effective at getting NSF funding to the right Researchers, attracting top talent to the research field, establishing best practices at cancer early detection, etc.
Generally, the optimally cost-effective organization for nonhuman animals (i.e., the organization we want to move money to) is going to be the one with the most management effectiveness (i.e., most able to efficiently carry out its interventions) among the set or organizations that have very high mission effectiveness with respect to our larger cause of reducing nonhuman animal suffering (i.e., those organizations that pick the optimal intervention or set of interventions for reducing nonhuman animal suffering).
The back-of-the-envelope calculation gets us some of the way to assessing mission and management effectiveness by taking these concepts into account, but looking at each of these two concepts more in depth from different angles can aid our assessment process.
I.2.d. Could it turn out that an organization has a mission effectiveness so high that their management effectiveness doesn’t matter?
Yes, though we currently consider this unlikely. While mission effectiveness might be dominant in calculating the impact from a donation, management effectiveness will matter a lot in complicated and more long-term ways as the organization seeks to scale up. Ultimately, it will always be better to donate to an organization that has high mission and management effectiveness.
Additionally, we have fairly wide confidence bars over estimates of the mission effectiveness at the moment, so it might be too risky to go “all in” on measures of mission effectiveness when issues of management effectiveness are raising red flags.
I.3. Criterion #3: The Organization is Working on Things That Seem to Have High Mission Effectiveness
I.3.a. How do we look for mission effectiveness?
It’s hard to assess mission effectiveness in a direct or easy way. What we intend to do is gather the relevant empirical evidence, expert testimony, and intuitions as to what interventions have high mission effectiveness and check to make sure the organization is working on employing these interventions.
However, there still is a strong need at moment to “keep an open mind” when it comes to interventions as the evidence base for nonhuman animal interventions is currently poor (for example, there is not yet any study with a control group, though several are now in development) and many potential interventions have not yet received any study. Thus, this criterion might be better used as a weak, heuristic approach to screen ineffective interventions out rather than screen effective interventions in.
I.3.b. What if a large organization has projects with both high and low mission effectiveness?
It’s important to note that when donating to an organization one is essentially donating to all of their projects and therefore is meeting them at their average mission effectiveness rather than their best. One might be tempted to think that this problem can be solved with restricted donations, however, this is generally not the case due to the problem of fungibility. Put simply, if an organization receives restricted funding to Effective Project #1, they can then use that donation to free up the unrestricted funding they would have put into Effective Project #1 and move that unrestricted funding to Ineffective Project #2. Thus, the donation did not accomplish any net increase to effective projects but rather resulted in a shift of funding, actually resulting instead in a net increase to ineffective projects.
I.3.c. Is pursuing a project with low mission effectiveness project grounds for disqualification?
This is a bit complicated. One might question an organization that is pursuing a project with low mission effectiveness as not really understanding success and failure (see Criterion #4 in section I.4). However, what does or does not have high mission effectiveness is not well-established and agreed upon, so perhaps the organization has a legitimate and justifiable difference of opinion.
Additionally, perhaps these ineffective projects are what draw in large amounts of donations from donors who are unconcerned with effectiveness, or perhaps these initiatives generate a lot of positive press for the organization, and therefore these projects have great indirect impact.
Therefore, it seems that pursuing a project with low mission effectiveness should be a negative, but not grounds for disqualification.
I.4. Criterion #4: The Organization Possesses A Robust and Agile Understanding of Success and Failure
I.4.a. What is a “robust understanding of success and failure”?
Now that we’ve assessed mission effectiveness, it’s time to turn our attention to management effectiveness. If an organization has high management effectiveness, it will very likely have what we call “a robust and agile understanding of success and failure”. This means the organization possesses detailed, thorough, and specific knowledge about what they want to achieve as an organization in the near and far term and what feedback would tell them whether they are moving toward or away from that mission and how they could move toward that mission better in a quick and iterative way. Put more simply, the organization can define “success”, knows what it looks like when they aren’t being successful, and acts in a way to gain quick feedback and update what they do.
I.4.b. Why was this included as a metric?
Unfortunately, in the non-profit world, feedback mechanisms are scarce. Unlike the for-profit world where a declining bottom line is apparent, non-profits merely need to convince themselves and donors that they are successful, not actually be successful. It’s very easy for a non-profit to keep spinning its wheels and think it is advancing on its mission, especially if its mission is vague and utopic. Therefore, it is important that savvy non-profits include checks to ensure they don’t get caught up in these traps and have an understanding of where they are going.
I.4.c. What would this look like? How would we find it in an organization?
To inquire into this metric, one should look at the website of the organization and the testimony of those working for the organization as to what mission they articulate and what plan they articulate for how to accomplish that mission.
Are their plans specific? Can they define outcomes that indicate success and failure as well as rationale for why those outcomes indicate success and failure? Do they care about self-assessment? Are they self-skeptical?
Is the organization actually measuring things? Are they measuring things with good methodologies? Are they measuring things that actually matter or are they just chasing certain metrics because they’re easy (i.e., measuring leaflets given instead of people converted)?
Moreover and most importantly, does the organization show a willingness to change in light of metrics pointing one way or another? If a leafleting organization found that online video ads were more effective or vice versa, would they make the switch? Has the organization made key changes in its methods before based on evidence collected?
An organization that is robust and agile with regard to success and failure should be taking cues, as relevant, from agile program management or lean start-up management, whereby they seek to try out a particular approach or intervention, learn from that approach, and then update their methods before trying again, continuing to iterate their methods in response to testing and evidence. If an organization is hitting many of these points, then they probably have a robust understanding of success and failure.
Additionally, such an organization will have goals that are SMART — specific, measurable, achievable, relevant, and time-bound. Good organizations will have well-targeted goals that they can use to concretely assess where they are, what they want to achieve, and how they will get there. Having a time-bound is especially important as it keeps the organization accountable to their expectations of success.
I.5. Criterion #5: The Organization Possesses a Strong Track Record of Success
I.5.a. What is a “strong track record of success”?
An organization that has high management effectiveness, by definition, should be able to accomplish its mission. Therefore, if the organization has been around long enough, it won’t be enough for them to understand what makes them successful, but they should generally be expected to have actually been successful by now and have accomplished some steps along the way to accomplishing their mission. Even if an organization has lofty goals that will take many years to accomplish (e.g., animal liberation), it still should have tractable subgoals that it has made progress on.
I.5.b. What would this look like? How would we find it in an organization?
It’s easy to look at an organization’s website for this information, as organizations usually like to share their claims of success in pages or newsletters. If that doesn’t work, one can always reach out to the organizations directly and ask what they’ve done so far with their donations. The real test will be carefully vetting the organization’s claims against common sense and evidence.
Generally, organizations—even potentially effective ones like those who have been evaluated by Giving What We Can—tend to overstate their accomplishments and we need to make sure these accomplishments have evidence to back them up. An example of how to do this is to try to elaborate all the claims the organization makes in a particular document and then provide sources for as many of them as possible (for examples, see the Giving What We Can evaluations of climate change organizations or the Copenhagen Consensus Report).
I.5.c. What if we’re considering a new and unproven organization?
Supporting an organization in its infancy might be a powerful way for ACE to have impact, as even small donations from ACE could make the difference between whether an eager start-up non-profit (much like ACE once was) happens or doesn’t happen. However, doing so is taking a bit of a risk, since you won’t have this criterion to look at and this criterion is one of the most objective and reliable measures of management effectiveness. This is a trade-off between risk and potentially higher rates of return that ACE would have to consider when evaluating.
I.6. Criterion #6: The Organization Has Strong Organizational Leadership and Structure
I.6.a. Why was this included as a metric?
An organization that has high management effectiveness will very likely have strong organizational leadership and structure as such things are paramount to how the organization operates. Bad or dysfunctional leadership can spell quick doom for the non-profits with even the highest mission effectiveness if not addressed.
I.6.b. What would this look like? How would we find it in an organization?
This can be identified by looking to the leadership structure and organization culture, looking specifically at the amount and competence of high-level staff, the quality and quantity of communication, and solid transition planning.
Generally, high-level staff should seem personable and competent on a gut level, be well known and liked among other related organizations, and be aware of each other’s responsibilities and procedures. Leadership should onboard new staff and volunteers up to speed with good intentional training structure to build capacity of individual staff and volunteers. New staff and volunteers should efficiently learn how to operate key programs and multiple staff and/or volunteers should have the training and knowledge necessary to operate key programs.
The organization should be able to survive upcoming transitions if the current leaders in the organization were to move onto different ventures and it would be good if the organization had a track-record of surviving similar transitions in the past. There should be strong internal documentation to ease staff transitions.
I.7. Criterion #7: The Organization is Transparent
I.7.a. Why was this included as a metric?
Transparency is the only way that ACE will get all the information it needs in order to properly evaluate the other six criteria, so it is an important metric to consider. However, an organization must go above and beyond this in order to meet this criterion. Transparency is very useful at identifying failure (see section 4) as it opens the organization to many channels of feedback and makes it harder to disguise problems. While an organization may be highly successful without being transparent and may have strong reason to not be transparent about some things, it seems like transparency will generally make an organization more likely to be successful.
Moreover, strong transparency makes the organization more useful to outsiders, as they can learn along with the organization (e.g., GiveWell and Effective Fundraising as two great examples).
Additionally, transparency is something that is worth encouraging on its own right for signalling purposes—we want more transparency in the charitable sector, so we make transparency one of our stated criteria.
I.7.b. What would this look like? How would we find it in an organization?
Does the organization claim to value transparency? Is the organization open with people who request information? Are they open to people who request information even if they’re not intending to donate or move large sums of money?
Better yet, does the organization publish reports online for all to see, not just to those who request it? Is the organization not afraid of publishing their mistakes and negative things about themselves? Do they achieve the gold standard and put a complete picture of themselves online in the style of AMF, the style of GiveWell, or the style of Charity Science, with full budgets, external reviews, audit reports, documentation of future plans, and other pertinent information?
II.The Cost-Effectiveness Calculation
Criterion #2 calls for a cost-effectiveness estimate of the non-profit. But how would this be estimated? What we’re looking for is an estimate of what outcomes would be produced per marginal dollar added to the funds of a particular organization. We can model this simply by looking to the following equation:
= Cost-Effectiveness, = Impact, = Upfront Costs,
= per-item costs, = number of items
This model states that cost-effectiveness equals impact divided by costs and then breaks cost down further (see section II.2 for more detail). Impact is not broken down further because it will vary depending on the context of the organization (see section II.1).
II.1. Understanding Impact
There are many different approaches to helping animals, such as working at pet shelters, leafleting, protesting in Chipotle, lobbying Congress for changes in the law, and many more. However, estimates of cost-effectiveness would be nearly useless without some common metric to compare across these widely different approaches. While we think that the weakness of comparative methods and the high uncertainty in these calculations make cost-effectiveness estimates only somewhat reliable (see section I.2.b. for more), it’s good to attempt this.
II.1.a. What would a common metric look like?
Following prior work by Peter Hurford and Brian Tomasik, we suggest evaluating things in terms of “days of animal suffering averted” (DASA) (though see possible refinements in section II.1.c.), which becomes DASA per dollar (DASA/$) when costs are taken into account (see section II.2). This is superior to other metrics, such as “vegetarians created per dollar” (used by Jeff Kaufman) because it allows us to compare across interventions that don’t involve generating vegetarians (e.g., lobbying) and also allows us to handle counterfactual adjustment better.
Whenever we approach a cost-effectiveness estimate for an organization, the evaluator would generate the appropriate equation for that organization with DASA/$ as the evaluand, and then evaluate it.
II.1.b. What might the calculations look like?
Let’s first consider vegetarian advocacy (e.g., leafleting, facebook ads, etc.) as a possible example. We suggest this equation:
= number of people swayed by the advocacy campaign,
= average net animals saved per opinion change,
= average time spent in a factory farm averted per animal saved
Something like a protest in Chipotle could be similar, though modeled with potential upside/downside:
Same as previous, but…
= summation of impact across all possible reactions of Chipotle,
= probability of that particular reaction,
= impact of that particular reaction
For a more complex but related intervention, we could consider investing money not in passing out leaflets, but in improving the design of the leaflets with the hope of convincing more people:
Same as previous, but…
= number of people swayed per leaflet of the new leaflet design,
= number of people swayed per leaflet of the old leaflet design,
= total times the new leaflet will be used
And advocacy like lobbying could be simple, but entirely different:
= Number of animals affected by the change in legislation (per day),
= how much their welfare is changed (relative to not being factory farmed at all),
=length of the change in legislation (in days),
= counterfactual share in producing the change accredited to organization
II.1.c. How might we refine these calculations?
While the formulas above are a good start, and probably good enough given the inherent uncertainty, there still are some issues we will have to take into account when creating and using these equations.
II.1.c.a. Accounting for specific details
First, it could be important to be sensitive to specific details about each opportunity and include that in the calculations. For example, the impact of any intervention that seeks to have impact by creating vegetarians should adjust the impact of vegetarians for product elasticity in the supply and demand of meat (i.e., AS should be adjusted downward to account for elasticity). Similar details might exist in other relevant calculations and should be identified.
II.1.c.b. Counterfactuals
Second, it is important to adjust for a proper counterfactual of what would have happened had the campaign not taken place. For example, if the lobbying never happened, how long would it take for the law change to happen anyway? If this organization didn’t accomplish the law change, would another organization have done it?
Sure, leafleting might have created 100 relevant opinion changes in favor of vegetarianism, but is it possible that many of these shifts happened because of things other than the leaflets? Will welfare changes for animals become moot because of some large shift in the future, like a hypothetical widespread adoption of in vitro meat?
Here, we would want to do things like adjust downward using a control group when evaluating advocacy, use terms like “CS” when evaluating lobbying, and other changes.
II.1.c.c. Variations within species / per food
Another complication is that each animal does not suffer identically and is not eaten equally by people. For example, theorists have pointed out that hens that are raised for meat seem to be in a position to suffer disproportionately more than other animals and are also a disproportionate share of the American diet. Others have pointed out that cows, being more cognitively complex, might instead suffer more.
Some of this is evened out by focusing on days of suffering (as hens raised for eggs are kept longer than other animals), but we still might want to focus on a per-animal basis, as some animals suffer more intensely per day than others. Jason Kirschner has suggested that we adopt a base unit of “meat-raised hen suffering” and convert everything into that.
We could adapt our equation for the DASA for advocacy to instead be the “days of meat-raised hen suffering averted” (DMRHSA) and add data about each animal individually, like so:
= number of opinion changes, = a summation across every relevant animal,
= the amount of that animal spared on average per opinion change,
= the number of days that animal suffers on average,
= the amount of suffering that animal endures on average relative to a meat-raised hen
Here, having values for , , and be able to differ for each animal will allow us to be more accurate in accounting for inter-animal differences, though this could come at a cost (see section II.1.c.h.).
II.1.c.d. Time discounting
Yet another aspect we haven’t considered much is “time discounting”. Is an animal spared five years from now worth the same to us as an animal spared right now? If there is a relevant difference this could greatly affect how we compare different interventions as some interventions (e.g., lobbying) operate at significant delay.
II.1.c.e. Indirect conversions
Another large component of cost-effectiveness that is currently missing from equations is the large variety of indirect effects. One prominent such effect is indirect conversions—for example, someone converting to a meat-reducing or vegetarian lifestyle not because of the influence of the campaign directly, but because of the influence of someone influenced by the campaign. One could even imagine this being very drawn out—for example, someone inspired to become an activist and start their own campaign because of the influence of a previous campaign, or a campaign influencing someone who influences someone who influences someone who influences someone, etc. How do we account for this, assuming we should?
II.1.c.f. Other indirect effects
Some other indirect effects exist of different magnitudes. Jason Kirschner points to one example—potential human suffering due to ostracism from converting to vegetarianism or veganism. Though this effect is probably very minute compared to the impact on the nonhuman animals, it’s possible that larger indirect effects may exist that have not yet been identified.
A much bigger example is that of meme spreading. Some theorists like Brian Tomasik and Robert Wiblin have speculated that meme spreading and the influence of those memes (e.g., the chance they prevent wild animal suffering from being spread via space colonization or promote feelings of non-discrimination toward substrates and therefore reduce future computational suffering, etc.) might be the dominant form of impact from spreading concern for animal suffering rather than the animals spared from factory farming in the interim.
Another big example might be learning. By performing an intervention we learn a fair amount about how that intervention is undertaken and this information can then be used to improve the effectiveness of future interventions, thereby improving future impact. This makes each intervention valuable not just for its own sake, but also in how it improves future interventions.
We’re currently not sure how to add such a potentially large and speculative impacts to the existing calculations, but given that a large majority of the impact might come from these effects, this could be a concern for our quantification.
II.1.c.g. Differences in certainty
After accounting for these many effects, we might also want to correct for another difference between calculations—certainty. For example, some estimates might be more affected by biases than other methods (e.g., non-response bias) and some estimates might just have different levels of certainty than others. One idea is to adjust each equation for the probability that we find that equation correct so as to make better comparisons.
II.1.c.h. More complicated than it’s worth?
A final concern might be that all these additional adjustments to the equation make them more complicated than they’re worth. Previously, Peter Hurford compared a simple equation to a far more complex equation and found that the difference between the resulting estimates was rather trivial, only differing by a factor of three. This means that simple calculations might still get at the right answer while also being easier to use, avoiding the human error.
Every step we add to the calculation is another chance to introduce uncertainty and error. Furthermore, the more demanding we make our equations, the more demanding we have to make our measurements to collect the relevant data for these calculations, which puts pressure on our methodology to be less friendly (e.g., longer surveys or more complex surveys that weaken response accuracy, etc.). Therefore, we might want to consider keeping it simple unless absolutely necessary and/or having both a simple and complex estimate in our calculations. Moreover, this increases the rationale of having certain safeguards, like having multiple independent evaluators create and evaluate the equations and relying heavily on criteria other than the cost-effectiveness estimate.
II.1.d. Making it about the organization?
So we now have equations that can evaluate the impact of individual interventions. It seems likely that the impact of a marginal dollar to a particular organization will be equivalent to the impact of a marginal dollar to the particular intervention the organization is most likely to marginally fund, but it’s possible this might not always be the case.
One example is that we might have uncertainty about which intervention the marginal dollar would fund (typical in a large organization working on many projects) and therefore we could adopt an approach like this:
= a summation across every possible intervention the org would fund,
= probability the marginal dollar will fund that particular intervention,
= DASA of that particular intervention
Another possible concern that exists on the organizational level is displacement in donations—by funding this organization, we may reduce other funding to that organization. This is a complex effect that is difficult to model, but that we may want to take into account.
There also may be other relevant ways that organizations differ from interventions in evaluation that I’m not aware of.
II.2. Understanding Costs
Understanding impact is important, but it’s only half the battle when it comes to cost-effectiveness—we also need to know how much it costs to buy that impact. Luckily, this should be a lot easier and have a lot less error than our calculations of impact.
To start, recall our cost-effectiveness model from earlier:
= Cost-Effectiveness, = Impact, = Upfront Costs,
= per-item costs, = number of items
We now know how to calculate on a case-by-case basis for each organization. Now we need to calculate costs, which we have modeled as equaling the sum of up-front costs and the product of per-item costs and the number of items.
II.2.a. Understanding per-item costs
We’re actually going to start backwards and begin with per-item costs, because that’s where the bulk of the expenses will be as we’ve visualized it. Per-item costs are anything that is paid on a per-X basis, like salaries, rental fees, printing costs for leaflets, phone calls to Congress, hosting fees for a website, Facebook ads, etc.
We can understand it like this:
= total per-item costs,
= summation of all items
= cost of that item,
= amount of that item
For example, imagine a leafleting campaign. Some per-item costs would be (1) the salaries of the employees and volunteers devoted to de leafleting, (2) the opportunity cost of each employee and volunteer, (3) and the costs of printing the leaflets, and (4) any relevant per-time overhead cost that contributes to the leafleting. One might think that if leafleting is 10% of the efforts of the organization, about 10% of the overhead cost should be attributed to leafleting, though this might not represent an accurate counterfactual about how the organization would scale back if it wasn’t leafleting.
So for leafleting, perhaps per-item costs would look like this:
= summation across all employees and volunteers,
= salary of that person, = opportunity cost of that person,
= time spent by that person, = cost of a leaflet,
= number of leaflets printed, = overhead cost of the org,
= share of overhead for leafleting
= length of the leafleting campaign
II.2.b. Understanding up-front costs
Up-front costs are the costs of undertaking the campaign that happen just once for the entire campaign. They include costs like the the cost of developing and creating the campaign, the cost necessary to train employees to be skilled enough to undertake the campaign, and the general overhead of running the organization, but do not include things like salaries or opportunity costs (as these are per unit of time) and do not include things like printing costs (as these are per item printed).
This leads us to an equation like this:
= upfront cost,
= development cost,
= training cost
II.3. Putting It All Together
Remember again the formula for cost-effectiveness:
= Cost-Effectiveness, = Impact, = Upfront Costs,
= per-item costs, = number of items
We now know enough to put everything together. Again, we think it’s most constructive to consider an example. Here’s a potential complete calculation for the days of animal suffering averted by leafleting:
= number of opinion changes, = average net animals saved per opinion change, = average time spent in a factory farm averted per animal saved, = summation across all employees and volunteers, = salary of that person, = opportunity cost of that person, = time spent by that person, = cost of a leaflet, = number of leaflets printed, = overhead cost of the org, = share of overhead for leafleting, = length of the leafleting campaign, = up-front development cost of campaign, = up-front training cost of campaign