Response to a Recent Critique of Our Research
Introduction
In this blog post we respond to a persistent critic of ACE’s work. Mr. Harrison Nathan has expressed concerns about our research and communications—in a recent online post he criticized our focus on effectiveness, our intervention evaluations, and our analysis of corporate outreach. We’ll focus on those three topics here.
We are a small staff of dedicated advocates and Researchers who strive for maximal transparency and open communication with our followers. For this reason, our email addresses are readily available on our website. Anyone who wishes to engage with us directly about our work is welcome to email any member of our staff; we will typically respond within 24 hours. We track online mentions of our name, but it is not our policy to respond directly to every mention—especially when we feel that most of the information we would provide in response is already available on our website (for instance, in our descriptions of our evaluation criteria, our cost-effectiveness estimates, and our policies). Still, we appreciate Mr. Nathan’s thoughtful and critical engagement with our work. We have decided that it may be useful to provide his recent criticism with a more detailed response, in order to allay certain misconceptions.
Table of Contents:
- Our Focus on Effectiveness and Other Ideological Concerns
- Our Leafleting Report and Use of Data
- Concerns About Corporate Outreach
- Closing Thoughts
Our Focus on Effectiveness and Other Ideological Concerns
ACE’s goal is to find and promote the most effective ways to help animals, whatever those may be. We strive for a world in which nonhuman animals live the best lives they can and suffer as little harm as possible, and we work to promote interventions and charities that we think will bring us closer to that ideal.
Given the limited resources of the animal advocacy movement—as well as the many ways we
might try to help nonhuman animals—we feel it is important to focus attention on areas where our efforts can be especially impactful. In particular, we believe that the vast scale and horror of industrial agriculture of farmed animals, its comparative tractability, and the relatively few resources brought to bear against it, make it an especially important arena in which to advocate for animals. For the same reasons, we support recent efforts to advocate for farmed fish—whether on the part of specialized charities, charities that work against many forms of factory farming like the Albert Schweitzer Foundation, or charities that promote alternatives to fish products like The Good Food Institute.1
Mr. Nathan suggests that there are certain charities which we would “probably never recommend” because of their stance “in support of animal rights as opposed to utilitarianism.” On the contrary, we consider any animal charity that we think is plausibly an impactful giving opportunity. It is true that many of our currently recommended charities include a commitment to reduce animal suffering as much as possible in their organizational philosophies; we find that organizations who actively try to maximize their effectiveness often adopt promising strategies for helping animals. We do not think, however, that only those organizations can be among the most impactful giving opportunities. We evaluate charities based on the outcomes we expect they can achieve, not whether they toe a particular ideological line.
Some charities can be highly effective in expectation by working for longer-term goals instead of more immediate improvements. Such charities can help bring abhorrent practices to light, galvanize the animal advocacy movement, and, at their best, achieve systemic change. Some such charities focus on securing animals’ rights. We recommend the Nonhuman Rights Project (NhRP) because we believe their work is a promising long-term route to a better world for nonhuman animals. NhRP’s campaigns (which currently focus on extending legal personhood to captive chimpanzees) seem unlikely to cause significant improvements in many animals’ lives in the short term. However, we feel that achieving legal rights for animals is sufficiently important that even slightly improving the likelihood of that legal reform has a high expected value. ACE also currently recommends The Good Food Institute and New Harvest, both of which are working towards long-term systemic change—although their efforts are also likely to reduce farmed animal suffering in the shorter term.
When deciding whether to recommend charities to donors, one of our major considerations is the existence of evidence indicating that they would be able to make good use of new donations. Historically, our recommendations direct several hundred thousand dollars per year to each of our Top Charities.2 As such, we generally restrict ourselves to recommending charities that have indicated a capacity for absorbing funding on this scale.3 The size of the charity can be an important indicator of this capacity, since smaller organizations may struggle to expand their operations in response to a major increase in donations. We also consider other evidence for charities’ room for more funding: in particular, whether they have concrete plans for expansion, and to what extent their track record indicates that those plans are achievable. In some cases, as Mr. Nathan notes, these factors may give us confidence that a small charity is capable of handling more donations than it is accustomed to.4
Our Leafleting Report and Use of Data
Mr. Nathan has been publicly critical of our 2014 leafleting report. Some of his concerns are addressed in our December 2016 blog post about common critiques, as well as our more recent general explanation of our use of data in making cost-effectiveness estimates.5 We will not detail much of our early thinking on leafleting here, as that thinking is documented in our 2014 report. We have stated clearly that the initial report does not represent our current views and publicly acknowledged that it was a mistake to wait until 2017 to update the report. We are currently working on an update that we intend to publish later this year.
We expect that the updated leafleting report will improve on our original leafleting report in a variety of ways by including (amongst other things):
- An in-depth discussion of the limitations of the available animal advocacy studies relevant to leafleting and the quality of the evidence that they provide
- A meta-analysis of the key results from what seem to be the most pertinent animal advocacy studies relevant to leafleting
- A detailed assessment of the various risks of bias in those most relevant animal advocacy studies
- A greater discussion of relevant literature from the social sciences
- Information from multiple case studies, as well as interviews with advocates who have a considerable amount of experience with leafleting
Because the field of animal advocacy research is quickly developing, we expect that our intervention reports might often go out of date within a few years of their initial publication, and plan to update them as needed.6 We now publish the date that each report was last updated at the top of each page.
The cost-effectiveness estimate in our 2014 leafleting report was derived from our assessment of the results of the 2013 Farm Sanctuary/Humane League Labs study (FS/HLL 2013). Mr. Nathan has stated that he thinks the outcome measure that we used to assess the results of that study lacked validity.7 One possible point of disagreement we have with Mr. Nathan is on the appropriate treatment of validity: we treat it as a continuous rather than a binary construct and he may treat it as a binary rather than a continuous construct. So while we agree with Mr. Nathan that the outcome measure in question wasn’t ideal, we believe that it possessed sufficient validity for it to truthfully describe important features of the results from the study in question. The outcome measure in question was able to importantly describe of-interest features of the reported data by accounting for the equivalent number of new lacto-ovo-vegetarians for farmed animals to some extent.8 Another favorable aspect of this measure in our opinion at the time was that it didn’t rely on the accuracy of self-reported consumption data as much as some other possible measures; it only relied on respondents to accurately report whether they completely avoided a product—rather than to precisely describe how much they had changed their consumption. Still, we didn’t pre-commit to the use of this outcome measure, and for that reason we don’t entirely rule out the possibility that our decision to use it was importantly influenced by some subconscious bias or biases.9
Mr. Nathan has also been critical of our use of the results from FS/HLL 2013 instead of the results from our own study to estimate the cost effectiveness of leafleting in our 2014 leafleting intervention report. The staff involved with the report who currently remain at ACE have limited recall regarding the rationale for this decision, and we are hesitant to speculate too heavily. Still, in the interest of transparency we list below what we believe were the likely reasons for why we preferred to base the cost-effectiveness estimate on the results from FS/HLL 2013:
- As we note in the original leafleting report, our 2013 leafleting study had a smaller sample size than that of the FS/HLL 2013. All else equal, smaller sample sizes mean one should have wider confidence intervals about the effects of a given intervention.
- At the time that we analyzed the results from our leafleting study, we had already completed a cost-effectiveness estimate for leafleting based on FS/HLL 2013. We preferred not to combine the results of the two studies because doing so would have involved a more complicated, time-consuming analysis that would have been more difficult to communicate.
- At the time of the analysis, we didn’t think that the leafleting cost-effectiveness estimate derived from FS/HLL 2013 was “absurdly high.”10 At that time, we were aware of several estimates of the effects of similar interventions that were similarly high.11
- At the time of the analysis, we were more familiar with the limitations of our own leafleting study than with the limitations of FS/HLL 2013.12
In retrospect, it may well have been an error on our part not to base our estimate of the cost-effectiveness of leaflets on our own leafleting study to a greater degree. As we have previously noted in detail, at the time of this analysis our team was very small and our research products were not subject to the same level of internal and external scrutiny that they are now. We agree with Mr. Nathan that there are a number of significant limitations to the results from FS/HLL 2013. Yet even when a study has limitations, it can still meaningfully reduce our uncertainty about the effects of an intervention. We think it is a mistake to assume that flawed research is worthless research. While poorly-conducted studies must be carefully analyzed to avoid misunderstanding their implications, ignoring their results entirely will often leave us less informed.
It is worth noting that we disagree with Mr. Nathan regarding what our 2013 study results showed about the effectiveness of leafleting. Mr. Nathan has claimed that our study “found no effect.”13 In fact, we did identify an effect in our analysis: statistically significant effects on the proportion of those who stopped eating red meat and poultry.14 These effects were supported by a later reanalysis.15 We think it is misleading for Mr. Nathan to repeatedly state that our leafleting study found no effect without acknowledging that our analysis did report the previously mentioned significant differences.
While it’s important to consider all available evidence, we believe it’s equally important to continue improving the quantity and quality of the evidence. Research is crucial to improving animal advocacy, and we are seeking to improve the movement’s research base in a variety of ways, including by administering the Animal Advocacy Research Fund.16 ACE also works continuously to improve our own research, establishing standards such as publicly pre-registering our analysis plans on the Open Science Framework to avoid ad-hoc decisions motivated by the data.17 We have also updated our research review process, assigning “primary critics” to all research content and calling on external reviewers to critique each major project before publication. We recently hired a research scientist with experience in animal advocacy research to pioneer our new experimental research division. We aim to continue improving the quantity and quality of advocacy research so that we can continue to improve our recommendations.
As Mr. Nathan points out, the fact that any given intervention can be implemented in many different ways presents a challenge for our intervention research, but it is a mistake to conclude that evaluating interventions as a class “doesn’t make much sense.” There are many ways to approach evaluating an intervention despite variation in its implementation. Some studies use multiple randomly assigned treatment groups with different versions of the relevant intervention. Some studies test which commonly used implementation of an intervention is most effective, so that other studies can test for the upper limit of the intervention’s effectiveness. All of these studies can provide evidence about the effectiveness of particular interventions across different modes of implementation.
Concerns About Corporate Outreach
The Number and Impact of Campaigns
Mr. Nathan’s assertion that “ACE doesn’t differentiate between policies according to their content” is simply not true. We do not just “tally” the number of corporate commitments each charity achieves.18 We have always considered the details of each policy to evaluate the impact it has for animals. For example, when we evaluated the impact of cage-free policies, we estimated that they improved conditions for laying hens by -25% to 46%.19, 20 In other words, our models are entirely consistent with the possibility Mr. Nathan suggests, that cage-free policies might actually make conditions worse for laying hens.
Since charities are generally consistent in the policies they encourage corporations to adopt, we can assume fairly uniform effects for each animal affected by a given campaign of a given organization. This is not the same as assuming the effects of all corporate concessions are equal. For a given organization’s campaigns, our primary considerations are the effects of the specific changes negotiated for, the number of animals they will affect, and the organization’s responsibility for these changes being adopted. As Mr. Nathan says, “a serious analysis [requires] examining the substance of policies.” Since policy demands are often fairly standardized across organizations and they tend to draw on relevant research, we believe it is well within ACE’s capacity to conduct such analyses. We also think it is possible to estimate the degree to which a given campaign leads to changes that would have happened regardless—though it may add significant uncertainty to our analysis.
Counterfactual Considerations
Mr. Nathan suggests that we overestimate the responsibility that charities bear for convincing corporations to commit to animal welfare reforms. In particular, he is skeptical that The Humane League (THL) was 90% responsible for the decision by United Egg Producers (UEP) to stop culling baby chicks. The new technology is more efficient, he argues, so groups like UEP would have eventually adopted it anyway.21
When we model the cost-effectiveness of a corporate campaign, we always consider the possibility that the corresponding policy change might, at least in part, be due to outside factors. We account for this possibility when we estimate each charity’s “responsibility for changes.” We estimated that THL was between 70% and 99% responsible for UEP’s recent pledge, since it was the only charity negotiating with UEP and in ovo sexing commitments were almost unprecedented at the time.22, 23
The number of corporate commitments that occur soon after specific-issue campaigns seems too great to be merely coincidental. Gestation crates were acknowledged as an issue by industry in the early 2000s, but it was not until the Humane Society of the United States ramped up their campaigns against gestation crates in 2012 that we saw a wave of corporate commitments to ban them. Similarly, there were a few early commitments to improve conditions for laying hens, mostly from companies with a strong welfare component to their branding. Then there was a wave of cage-free policies drafted by dining services providers (first at individual locations and then throughout their operations) which coincided closely with campaigns by THL. Following this, there was a wave of policy commitments through other sectors, again coinciding closely with campaigns by advocacy groups.
To our knowledge, corporations have only rarely committed to policies that improve welfare unprompted, even when such changes appear to benefit their bottom line.24 For example, the PETA page Mr. Nathan quotes regarding the profitability of controlled-atmosphere killing (CAK) also claims that “despite the clear benefits of CAK over electric immobilization and its minimal ROI [return-on-investment] time, North American poultry companies have been slow to adopt it.” We are not aware of any major effort on the part of the animal agriculture industry to implement any of the reforms that animal advocates might lobby for. As a result, we find it unlikely that companies which adopt a policy just after becoming the target of a campaign would have adopted the same policy at the same time without those efforts.
Still, we assume that each commitment only impacts animals for a limited amount of time (usually about one to 15 years, with an estimated mean duration of about 5 years). This is consistent with the possibility that outreach campaigns simply cause corporations to make policy changes sooner than they otherwise would have.
Uncertainty Regarding Adherence
The fact that corporate commitments are nonbinding is a concern for us. The history of corporations making these pledges on a large scale in the U.S. is quite short. We hope to have a better understanding of the long-term impact of these commitments in a few years. Groups like Compassion in World Farming are already working to track and follow up with corporations, and we’re watching to see what happens.25 Part of our motivation for assuming that most commitments will lead to between one and 15 years of impact for animals includes our countenancing the possibility that corporations temporarily adopt new practices in response to campaigns, but eventually return to their previous practices.
Mr. Nathan is particularly concerned about the wording of the UEP’s pledge to use in ovo sexing technology to eliminate the culling of male chicks, which states they will do so “by 2020 or as soon as it is commercially available and economically feasible.” He claims that this technology “was developed by industry because it is more efficient than the current method,” and seems to believe that the poultry industry would likely adopt it regardless of THL’s work. In reality, the technology is still very much in development, and it is unclear if or when the poultry industry would be incentivized to adopt it on their own. Furthermore, though they may end up being beneficial to the poultry industry in the long run, most egg sexing projects are not being developed by said industry.26 While they have seen some success in lab settings, none of the in ovo methods we are aware of have been implemented on an industrial scale. Considering the speed, accuracy, and cost effectiveness required of techniques used at a large scale, we think it quite possible that the technology will not be viable by 2020. (This would have been an even more plausible possibility when the pledge was made in June 2016, prior to the publication of several recent advances.)
Given the situation, we believe THL’s approach was reasonable. Once in ovo sexing becomes available on an industrial scale, the pledge gives THL grounds to campaign against UEP should they not adopt the technology—especially after 2020. Since galvanizing public outrage about the harms of chick culling seems particularly tractable, we think the threat of a campaign gives THL significant leverage to demand that UEP replace culling with in ovo sexing, even if it proves to be more expensive.27
The Impact of Broiler Reforms
Animal charities have begun to push for companies to use breeds of broiler chicken that experience higher welfare; requirements to do so are now part of many charities’ broiler campaigns. However, due to the selection practices historically implemented by breeders, most breeds that have higher welfare are also slower to grow than the fast-growing breeds currently being raised.28
We do not believe that corporations will slaughter these slower-growing chickens at a lower weight than faster-growing chickens. Rather, they will likely allow the slower-growing chickens to live longer so that they can be slaughtered at the same weight as their faster-growing counterparts. In other words, we believe these reforms might cause chickens to live slightly better but slightly longer lives.
We understand the concern that these broiler reforms will still reduce the net welfare of broiler chickens, due to their longer lives being spent in poor conditions. In fact, we accounted for this possibility in our 2016 cost-effectiveness estimate for Mercy For Animals (MFA). We estimated that the commitment MFA secured from Perdue would improve conditions for broiler chickens by -25% to 40%, noting that a “major risk” of the commitment is that “the additional days of suffering due to slower growth” might outweigh the welfare improvements.29 In other words, we think it is likely that adopting these broiler reforms will cause an overall improvement in the welfare of chickens, but we do not assume this to be the case.
While the evidence on the matter is not conclusive, we believe it is unlikely that broiler reforms will lead to a greater number of chickens being raised by the poultry industry. As Mr. Nathan notes, a recent industry document claims that 15% more slow-growing chickens would have to be raised to yield the same amount of ‘prime’ meat, even if they were slaughtered at the same weight as faster-growing chickens.30 However, an older Poultry World study indicates that slow- and fast-growing broilers slaughtered at near the same weight yielded very similar proportions of leg, breast, and wing meat. The evidence and reasoning behind the industry report is unclear, so it is difficult to assess its claims—though there could well be differences between the study’s conditions and prospective industry procedures.
There are also reasons to think that poultry reforms might reduce the number of broiler chickens raised. The Poultry World study suggests that higher-welfare chicken breeds will have lower mortality rates than the broiler chickens currently being farmed. The aforementioned industry document also indicates that the new breeds could lead to cost increases as high as 49% due to their longer lives and increased metabolism.31 This could lead companies to raise the price of chicken meat, which has the potential to significantly lower demand; price elasticity research from 2010 indicates a poultry price increase of 49% would reduce demand by between 22% and 45%.32
Overall, we feel that our weighting of the potential risks and benefits of broiler reforms has been reasonable and supported by the available evidence. We think the likelihood that reforms will lead to more chickens being raised is far lower than Mr. Nathan seems to believe, but our models still account for that possibility. Our estimates of the effect of broiler reforms involve a significant amount of uncertainty, and will benefit from further evidence; at present, we believe these programs are promising on balance.
Closing Thoughts
As an effective altruist organization, one of our fundamental values is a willingness to revise our approach based on new information. ACE is not wedded to the notion of any particular organization or intervention being effective. What matters to us is finding and supporting organizations that help animals through evidence-backed, impactful work. We are committed to updating our evaluations regularly because the landscape of charities constantly evolves, as does our own thinking. We believe that our current recommendations are exceptionally strong giving opportunities, but we are always looking for new charities that are even better at helping animals.
As we’ve written about at length, our conclusions are often uncertain. In particular, our cost-effectiveness models sometimes must rely on estimates and subjective judgment calls. They provide ranges of expected value, but should not be assumed to literally calculate the amount of good that charities or interventions do. We have sometimes struggled to communicate the proper level of caution to take in interpreting our estimates. To better indicate the uncertainty of our cost-effectiveness estimates, we now express them as subjective confidence intervals33 (SCIs) rather than single values. Expressing estimates as ranges helps communicate not only our degree of uncertainty, but the simple presence of uncertainty—making them less prone to misinterpretation.
We continue to make and publish quantitative cost-effectiveness models because they support our mission, they are useful for making direct comparisons, and they increase our transparency. Our models help us assess the implications of current research for particular interventions and determine what further research would most influence our future recommendations. They also allow our readers to identify specific points of contention. If our evaluations were entirely qualitative in nature, it might be harder for people who disagree with us about the effectiveness of a program to pinpoint the source of their disagreement, since our qualitative statements are more open to interpretation than structured, quantitative ones.
There is room for reasonable disagreement about some of the estimates we use in our CEEs; that’s precisely why we publish our full models and provide all of our reasoning. Any reader who disagrees with one of our estimates is free to take that into account when they consider where to donate. We invite donors to trust us, but we also provide all of our reasoning so that donors need not simply trust us; they can read our models and make their own decisions.
We are grateful to anyone in the animal advocacy community who draws our attention to potential problems with our thinking or our recommendations. Since our entire staff is highly passionate about animal advocacy, we are happy to have the opportunity to discuss it with any interested parties. We strive to give timely responses to each individual, but need to direct our limited staff time towards research projects as well. So although we may not always be able to compose formal detailed public responses, anyone who wishes to engage us in conversation is always welcome to comment on our blog posts, respond on our Facebook page, or directly email any member of our staff.
Fish Feel, the fish advocacy organization mentioned by Mr. Nathan, appears to have been founded in June 2015. The Albert Schweitzer Foundation’s first success in farmed fish advocacy took place in late 2015, and The Good Food Institute was founded in October 2015 and began operations in February 2016. The relative nascency of effective farmed fish advocacy has limited ACE’s ability to recommend fish advocacy organizations, but we look forward to considering more such charities as the field continues to grow.
Donations moved to Standout Charities have been less well-monitored; we aim to study them in more depth this
year. In the future, we will continue to look for ways to recommend promising charities without directing more funds to them than they can manage. One way we may do this is by recommending that donors spread their giving across our charities in proportion to their estimated funding gaps.
Mr. Nathan states: “Additionally, ACE requires that charities have ‘room for more funding,’ which in practice means requiring that they have already attained a certain size (unless ACE decides that a charity can use donations many times greater than its budget, as it did when it first recommended Animal Equality.)”
We address points Mr. Nathan has raised in the sections of our post titled “Our Current Leafleting Report and Using Older, Less Rigorous Data,” “The Usefulness of Cost-effectiveness Calculations,” “Recommendations of GFI and New Harvest,” and “Conflicts of Interest.”
In addition to the leafleting report update currently in progress, we made a major update to our online ads report in August 2016.
For instance, “the sole basis of the estimate is ACE’s strange interpretation wherein five vegetarians could be “patched together” (ACE’s own words) from the results of the study, which actually found that just one person became vegetarian. This post hoc construct obviously lacks validity, and resulted in an absurdly high estimate, suggesting that it requires less than five dollars to create the equivalent of a new vegetarian.”一Harrison Nathan, Re-evaluating Animal Charity Evaluators.
At the time, what was of interest to us was the number of new lacto-ovo-vegetarian equivalents rather than just the number of new lacto-ovo-vegetarians. This is because we thought that in some cases partial lacto-ovo-vegetarians (i.e., those who avoid just one of, or some subset of, red meat, chicken, and fish) could be amalgamated to be the equivalent to one lacto-ovo-vegetarian. For instance, if one respondent reported they newly avoiding red meat, another respondent reported newly avoiding chicken and another respondent reported newly avoiding fish, then in terms of their new avoidance of animal products those three respondents were one new lacto-ovo-vegetarian equivalent.
Human reasoning can be subject to many cognitive biases. At least partly as a result of this, in a significant amount of scientific literature, Researcher degrees of freedom can lead to suboptimal analysis choices. Pre-analysis plans are a promising method for lessening the Researcher degrees of freedom involved in analytic decisions and thus hopefully lessening the influence of cognitive biases on analytic decisions.
“Moreover, the sole basis of the estimate is ACE’s strange interpretation wherein five vegetarians could be “patched together” (ACE’s own words) from the results of the study, which actually found that just one person became vegetarian. This post hoc construct obviously lacks validity, and resulted in an absurdly high estimate, suggesting that it requires less than five dollars to create the equivalent of a new vegetarian.”—Harrison Nathan, Re-evaluating Animal Charity Evaluators.
These limitations include the lack of a control group, as well as the suboptimal question wording and ordering which caused a high risk of social desirability bias.
“ACE had two studies available: one which found no effect, and another […] which was interpreted as showing a very large effect. ACE’s estimate ignored the former and was based entirely on the latter.”—Harrison Nathan, Re-evaluating Animal Charity Evaluators.
E.g., “The confidence intervals for red meat and poultry were (2.0%, 11.5%) and (0.9%, 8.7%) respectively.” “We found support for claims that distributing leaflets from Vegan Outreach (or similar leaflets published by other groups) causes a small percentage of respondents to go vegetarian or give up eating specific types of meat.”
E.g., “The connection between the treatment leaflet and elimination of red meat and poultry was statistically significant.”
So far, our funded projects have included a variety of randomized controlled trials evaluating different outreach methods, as well as research on movement building and the psychology of diet change.
We require the same of studies supported by the Animal Advocacy Research Fund.
ACE does not consider the number of agreements reached to be an important outcome in itself; what’s important to us is how much an organization’s work improves animal well-being. We keep track of corporate pledge counts because they indicate the scale and strategy of charities’ corporate outreach efforts, not because they feed into our effectiveness estimates. When our reviews mention such numbers, they are brought up in passing, and for similar reasons: to give a rough sense of how a charity’s outreach program operates.
These values represent a subjective confidence interval (SCI). A subjective confidence interval is a range of values that communicates judgments about an unknown quantity. We typically construct a 90% subjective confidence interval such that, given our models and the information available to us, we feel 90% confident that the true cost effectiveness value falls within the range given, and feel that the true value is equally likely to fall above or below this range. We will discuss our use of SCIs in more depth on a forthcoming web page.
See cell PMI, labeled “Proportional improvement in welfare due to cage-free policies.” The variable’s distribution is assumed to be normal, with a 5th percentile of –.25 and a 95th percentile of .46. (Note that while the linked cost-effectiveness calculation is for The Humane League, we used the same estimate in all 2016 cost-effectiveness calculations involving organizations conducting cage-free campaigns, including Mercy For Animals, the Albert Schweitzer Foundation, and HSUS’s Farm Animal Protection Campaign).
Mr. Nathan claims that in ovo sexing technology “was developed by the industry because it is more efficient than the current method.” Given this belief, it seems likely that Mr. Nathan also believes that egg producers would be interested in adopting this technology fairly soon irrespective of their commitment to The Humane League to do so by 2020.
See cell TSR1, labeled “THL’s responsibility for changes.” The variable’s distribution is modeled as a beta distribution with alpha equal to 9 and beta equal to 1. We felt that THL’s contribution to other campaigns (cell TSR) was weaker; we modeled its distribution as a beta distribution with alpha equal to 4 and beta equal to 6.
To our knowledge, the UEP pledge rested on the plausibility of accurate industrial-scale sexing, not the existence of any particular research group. Our limited understanding is that there are several promising approaches to this technology, many of which appear to be fairly straightforward variations on common analytical methods such as DNA assays, fluorescence and Raman spectroscopy, and egg candling combined with infrared spectroscopy.
Given their apparent diversity and relative simplicity, we do not think a world where none of these avenues are pursued by Researchers is a very plausible counterfactual. Thus, we do not believe there are strong research-related counterfactual effects on UEP’s decision to take on the pledge. (While the work of a particular research group might lead to the early development of cheap in ovo sexing technology that obviates the UEP pledge, this possibility is best incorporated into the “years of impact expected” parameter of our models, which in part represents the amount by which a given pledge speeds up the enactment of a promised change.)
Deep consideration of any counterfactual question raises some complex concerns, and considering chains of causality is an extremely challenging task unless they are fairly short. In our work, we have usually tried to keep the picture simple, taking many background effects as fixed and assigning most of the responsibility to a small number of known entities that are clearly involved in a given situation.
Overall, the assignment of responsibility is a complex question and one we hope to consider further, possibly in the form of a dedicated post.
The main exceptions we are aware of are some companies claiming to have proactively taken steps to improve treatment for laying hens in 2014, as well as some corporations following competitors’ leads on welfare reforms. In both cases, some of the impetus for the change can be attributed to the charities that campaigned for these policy changes, making them more salient and perhaps more risky not to adopt. There are also a small number of companies which make leading the curve on animal welfare a key part of their brands, whose decision making may only be affected by animal advocates fairly indirectly (if at all).
Additional welfare commitment trackers are available here and here.
We know of one project completely funded by the poultry industry, and one startup supported by the Dutch government. Other projects are being developed by Researchers at the University of Dresden, as well as in collaborations between the Universities of Leipzig and Dresden and between the University of Edinburgh and diagnostics company Hologic.
It is true that actually carrying out such a campaign would take more of THL’s resources, and would not necessarily succeed. However, given THL’s expertise in negative campaigns and the apparent tractability of organizing opposition to chick culling, we think it likely that such a campaign would be relatively low-cost and effective—making the threat of the campaign a particularly powerful deterrent.
An industry document claims that the suggested breeds take 32% more time than fast-growth broilers take to grow to the traditional size of fast-growth broilers at slaughter.
See cell PMI1, labeled “Proportional improvement in welfare due to improved policies.” The variable’s distribution is modeled as normal, with a 5th percentile of –.25 and a 95th percentile of .4.
“Prime” meat is here used to refer to the breasts, wings, legs, and thighs of broiler chickens.
See page 6 of the industry document.
This range is our 90% subjective confidence interval. A meta-analysis found the price elasticity for poultry to be between –.44 and –.92.
A subjective confidence interval is a range of values that communicates judgments about an unknown quantity. We typically construct a 90% subjective confidence interval such that, given our models and the information available to us, we feel 90% confident that the true cost effectiveness value falls within the range given, and feel that the true value is equally likely to fall above or below this range. We will discuss our use of SCIs in more depth on a forthcoming ACE web page.
Filed Under: Transparency Tagged With: criticism, interventions, leafleting